Sidebilder
PDF
ePub

followed by European steel manufacturers in our market. The then status of American steel manufacturers is shown by the proven experience of the Carnegie Steel Company. It was the most aggressive of any of the steel companies to enter foreign trade, exporting 70 per cent of the then steel exports. The Carnegie Company's location, facilities and freight rates enabled it better than most other companies to enter foreign trade, and from its works, as the foreign trade of the Steel Corporation developed, such trade to the extent of 24 per cent of the entire product of the Carnegie Company goes into such export trade. It will therefore appear that the Carnegie Company can be fairly regarded as the best fitted of American steel companies to compete for export trade. Referring to that time, the president of that company testified:

We had made spasmodic attempts at it. In dull times when business could not be secured at home, we would make attempts at foreign business by going in and making an unusual price, which was the only way that any foreign business could be secured then, inasmuch as we had not an established business or business connection, and therefore customers were not inclined to buy from a firm who could only furnish them occasionally.

The relation of the Carnegie Company to foreign trade is shown by its minutes. From the proofs in the case three things seem settled, namely: That when the steel Corporation was formed American steel manufacturers had no real dependable export trade abroad; that such sales as they made were spasmodic, made with a view to dumping surplus product; and such sales were secured by underselling the European market when they had no home market. It will also appear that being excluded by the steel tariffs of Germany, France, Russia, Austria and Italy, and by other causes from England, such dependable foreign markets as were open for them to build up, as will be seen later, had to be found in other parts of the world. This summary of the situation is warranted by the study of the proofs. Seeing, then, that when the Steel Corporation was formed, no such volume of foreign trade in steel existed; that the acquisition of any part, or indeed the whole of it, could constitute

a restraint of trade with other countries; and seeing that the foreign trade which the Steel Corporation had during its earlier years had increased from approximately $31,000,000 to $91,000,000 we turn to the next question, Did the Steel Company acquire this original or additional trade by monopolizing or restraining foreign trade, or attempting to do so; or, on the other hand, was its acquisition the natural and normal growth of fair business effort? We have said the foreign trade of the Steel Company in 1911 was $91,000,000, but of that amount some $30,000,000 is really not solely its own, but was shared by it with other American steel manufacturers. To explain, it will hereafter appear that in the development of a foreign steel trade, the Steel Corporation has established agencies, warehouses, freight communications and other exporting agencies in many of the markets of the world. As we read the testimony, in reference to this $30,000,000 of foreign trade, it seems that if an American manufacturer of steel finished products, for example, locomotives, oil tanks, gas tanks, cars, etc., had an inquiry, or desired to make a bid to furnish such goods in some foreign country, where such manufacturer did not have, but the Steel Corporation did have, a representative, the Steel Corporation would, on request, ascertain and report to the American tank manufacturer what price he would have to put on his tanks, etc., to get into the desired foreign market. of the tankmaker to meet such foreign competitive price in the prospective buyer's market depended, amongst other things, on two items the cost of the sheets from which his tank was made, and the freight cost of delivering the tank. In case the current prices of such sheets in the American steel market were such that the tankmaker could not sell his tank low enough to compete with the foreign bidder the Steel Corporation would agree to furnish the plates at such lower price as would enable the tankmaker to underbid his foreign competitor. This price reduction, coupled with the fact that the Steel Corporation would forward the tanks with its own freight, enabled the tankmaker and the Steel Corporation to thus jointly sell the tank, which neither could do alone. By such operations, where it made the basic material, but did not make the finished article,

--

The ability

the Steel Corporation, in 1911, thus did $30,000,000 in trade abroad in finished steel products in coöperation with other American manufacturers. The proofs show that this course of price reduction was followed in order to induce American manufacturers of finished steel products to coöperate with the Steel Corporation in extending the latter's foreign trade. The uncontradicted proof in that regard is that these foreign reduction prices thus given to American manufacturers to enable them to compete in the foreign markets were "open to all comers; anybody that wanted to develop a foreign business received our assistance, not only in the way of special prices, but we would lend him a salesman in a foreign country and place our office at his disposal and help him in every way to build up a foreign business. . . . Our office is an encyclopedia for the manufacturers of the United States, particularly in iron and steel and those collateral lines. We have never hesitated to give information with regard to conditions in countries, and the credit of people whom we may have been doing business with, and especially facilities and information generally with regard to tariffs in countries and railway facilities for internal distribution generally. . . . I had prepared under my direction a list, I think, of about 158 manufacturers to whom we have made a special allowance in order to enable them to develop a foreign business."

The proofs show that this large volume of business, termed by the Steel Company "reëxport" business, and amounting, as stated, to $30,000,000 in 1911, was shared in by 158 other firms or companies, and in making such reëxport articles from 15,000 to 18,000 men were employed. The proof is that on ocean freights the Steel Corporation had no rebate or advantage over its competitors. It will be observed that in thus reducing the price of basic steel materials to enable manufacturers to enter the foreign markets, the Steel Corporation has pursued the same helpful course of lower freights for exports which the Interstate Commerce Commission has, since 1903, approved of the railroads doing. In that regard the proofs show if a shipment is made from Pittsburgh to New York under a bill of lading beginning and ending with Pittsburgh and New York, that

where it is known that it is going to be exported the rate is less than when it is known it is going to stop in New York; the tariffs are published. . . . There is an export rate and a domestic rate, and the government has encouraged the export business to the extent of permitting the Interstate Commerce Commission to make export rates. The export rates have been in effect since 1903.

And we may add the proofs show that the Interstate Commerce Commission has gone to the extent of differentiating among different articles for export, making freights on export rails lower than on other export articles. We may here say that the Interstate Commerce Commission and the railroads in thus coöperating with the Steel Corporation, and these other manufacturers in allowing lower freights from interior points to the seaboard on goods intended for export, have followed the policy adopted in European countries. In that regard the proofs show:

The German government and the German railroads help for the export of finished products, but they charge the full domestic rate for any finished product that is imported.

Passing on, then, from this $30,000,000 of the foreign trade which the Steel Company has created for itself by inducing domestic consumers of its basic products to jointly enter into a foreign trade, and considering the other foreign trade, $60,000,ooo, which is its own, we examine the evidence as to whether the creation and building up of this, its own foreign trade, involves monopoly or restraint of trade. This becomes all-important, because the Steel Corporation contends that the creation and building up of a foreign steel and iron trade was one of the controlling reasons that led to its formation, and not a purpose to restrain or monopolize interstate home trade. that regard the contention of the Steel Corporation is that no such foreign steel and iron trade could be built up without the large resources of the Steel Company, and the varied products which the integration and combination of its units alone made possible. The mere statement of this contention shows its importance, for if the twofold purpose of this statute is to foster

In

and protect trade, both foreign and interstate, and if foreign trade cannot be increased without some such mechanically varied and financially strong agency as this Steel Corporation, then manifestly such agency is not a violation of a statute whose purpose was to permit - not to prevent the normal, natural and to be desired development of unrestrained, unmonopolized trade, both foreign and domestic. In taking up this question, we dismiss once and for all the question of mere volume or bigness of business. The question before us is not how much business was done, or how large the company that did it—the vital question is, how was the business, whether big or little, done was it, in the test of the Supreme Court, done by prejudicing the public interests, by unduly restricting or unduly obstructing trade? The question is one of undue restriction or obstruction of trade, and not of undue volume of trade. If mere size were the test of monopoly and trade restraint, we have not one, but a half dozen unlawful monopolies in the large department stores of a single city. If a manufacturing and selling business, fully equipped for its local market, extends its operations to cover a state, its business, its facilities, its capital, must grow larger. If it is to cover nations, it must be larger still. These plain facts simply buttress the holdings by courts that the normal and necessary expansion of business to any size is not forbidden by the Sherman Law, unless such expansion is accompanied or accomplished by an undue restraint or obstruction of trade.

Turning, then, to this foreign trade, we find that in 1901 the Steel Corporation did a foreign trade of $31,000,000, and in 1911 of $91,000,000. This was 90 per cent of the foreign iron and steel trade of the country. On the one hand, it is charged that this foreign trade was acquired by violation of the Sherman Act; on the other, that it is the normal and natural result of lawful business, commercial foresight and persistent effort. To determine these contentions from the evidence, we now address ourselves. Of the purpose of this corporation to create and possess this foreign trade, there can be no question. So that, if it was illegally done, the company cannot escape the legal consequences.

Its avowed purpose to enter into and ac

« ForrigeFortsett »