Sidebilder
PDF
ePub

economic phenomena in their historical development when he presents them not as things technical and apart, but as merely special aspects of a complex whole, and intelligible only in the light of a social theory. The economists may, if they please, rail at the sociologists, but they should recognize that economics is meaningless except as part of a broader social science. So great indeed, is the need of this new science of society, which shall cover things ethical, legal, economic and political, as well as many others, and which shall be neither a collection of "dessicated anthropological anecdotes," to borrow H. G. Wells' description, nor yet a web of vague abstractions, that contributions to it should be heartily encouraged, and should be judged most charitably. This new field is so vast and difficult that pioneers in it must inevitably stray and stumble. Yet the report of every explorer will be of service if it narrates truly what he saw in the undiscovered country, and describes his route accurately, that others may follow it and make it the starting point of fresh investigation. Leaving the metaphor, the scholar who proposes a new theory of social development must be an attentive and impartial observer of fact, and must be logical in his generalization, else he wastes the time of himself and others. Loria appears to me, in his handling both of theory and of history, to fall below a fair standard of professional competence. I shall not attempt to describe or to criticize the book in detail, but shall seek merely to indicate some of the faults which make it not worth the reading.

As Loria's book is devoted to the determination of "The Laws of Income " the reader wants, first of all, to know what the author means by income. A statement on page 29 appears, by its form and emphasis, to be offered as a definition: "the surplus product of coercively associated labor, after there has been subtracted from that product what is required for the redintegration and increase of the subsistence of the laborers and of the technical capital, constitutes income." Disregarding for the present that element of the concept which restricts it to a certain form of organization ("coercive association") the feature which strikes one most

is the division of the social product, of which part only is income. The term income, as used by Loria, departs in its very conception from the conventional idea of a colorless mathematical total; it has a social significance, it suggests the contrast between the beati possidentes and the rest of us. Now let us admit, candidly, that this brings to the forefront a question which has been of the most absorbing interest in all ages. Let us admit further that this question is one which conventional economics has been and always will be incompetent to solve. Sympathize as we may with Loria in his quest, I do not see how any reader of the book can feel that he has done more than to pass the socialists on a false road, on which they have recently been retracing their steps. He fails, as they have done, to distinguish in history any influences which have fixed the returns to laborers at a point capable of precise objective definition. He does not even attempt to develop a theory of population, to supplement the theory of land monopoly which he has presented in earlier works. His definition itself wavers in the face of facts. Subsistence appears first as "required," necessary," "bare"; it " is a precise quantity "; then it is "quasi fixed," it "remains unaltered or nearly so "; it "does not of necessity coincide with the strict necessaries of life "; we are asked to consider cases in which subsistence diminishes, and other cases in which it increases until it " at length annexes a certain share of income "; finally, we are told of processes, of the first importance in the workings of the economic system, by which subsistence is "artificially" lowered to keep laborers from the land, and by which, in the conflict between subsistence and income, "in the last resort, the arbiter in the contest is income, and [that] subsistence becomes established at that point which gives the maximum permanent income."

[ocr errors]

"No more logical demand can possibly be made," writes Loria on one of the early pages of his book, "than that we should distinguish clearly between subsistence and income, defining the latter as that part of the net product which remains after subtracting the subsistence of the laborers." The reader, ignorant as yet of the way in which the definition

of subsistence is going to fail him, starts hopefully only to plunge immediately into an obscurity from which he will never emerge. A discussion of the relation of capital and income, which seems academic, leads to the conclusion that "if that part of the product which should go to redintegrate the technical capital and the subsistences, is produced and consumed instead in the form of articles of consumption which, from the nature of the case, are not periodically reproduced, it is not income." The relatively simple concept of income, as the surplus product of coercively associated labor, is modified in many ways. Wealth, whatever may be its origin, which passes to unproductive members of society, such as thieves, gamblers, or beggars, is not income. "The income of the owner of a house which is rented by laborers, the income of a retailer, a money-lender, or a doctor, being the incomes derived from the slender purses of the workers, represent a quantity of wealth taken from subsistence to be transformed into income; in other words it no longer represents a simple transference of pre-existent income from one individual to another, but a positive increment to the total income." Unclaimed inheritances" continue to produce an income, although there is no recipient." Incomes are

deposited in a bank." The quantity of incomes produced in a nation" is determined by the quantity of capital productively employed, by the quantity and productivity of the land, by the quantity of public or private securities issued."

Some of this elaboration of the concept of income is harmless, tho it is relatively useless for the purposes of an author who seeks to rise above the limitations of space and time. On the other hand, the constant shifting in the meaning of such terms as subsistence and income tempts Loria constantly to choose in any particular case the meaning which best suits the purpose of his argument; and makes the book interesting throughout as an example of faulty logic rather than as a contribution to knowledge. It seems a pity that Loria, who in referring to Marx uses the terms surplus-value and income as interchangeable and appears, therefore, to recognize the likeness of his concept to that of the socialists, should take up

the fight which they waged with so much vigor and learning at the very time when they are beginning to recognize defeat.

To this suggestion Loria's reply would doubtless be that his distinction of subsistence and income, while it assumes class divisions in the recent period much like those of socialist theory, rests still on a very different theory of historical development. Loria, namely, distinguishes three forms of income. "In the first of these, undifferentiated income, labour is completely conjoined with the ownership of the means of production and with income. In the second, differentiated income, labour is completely disjoined from the ownership of the means of production and from income. In the third, mixed income, labour may be partially or wholly disjoined from the ownership of the means of production, but it is always partially conjoined with income." The first two forms are dominant and fundamental, occupying in turn almost the whole of the economic field, while the third, in which the worker receives more than a bare living, occupies merely a secondary place, and "is constrained to subordinate its own development to the rules prescribed by that pure form of income which is at the time predominant." Loria, having fortified himself against the attacks of critics, first, by giving such a hazy definition of income as a whole that it is quite impossible in any given case to distinguish it from subsistence, and then, by conceding that laborers do sometimes receive " income even when they are not owners of the means of production, proceeds in general on the assumption that the class receiving" mixed income," i. e., workers getting something more than a bare living, is negligible. History presents itself to him as the opposition of two extreme forms. If "we study the succession of the forms of income in the course of economic evolution, we see that this evolution begins with undifferentiated income in the primitive communist economy, passes then to differentiated income in the slave-holding system, and that this form of income persists in the subsequent serf-economy, to lead back, however, to undifferentiated income with the rise of the guilds; under the wage system we return to differentiated income, and only

sporadically is this system contrasted by a more evolved form of undifferentiated income, the coöperative economy."

The "primitive communist economy" has long been the happy hunting ground of theorists. Many years have passed, however, since Kemble (1848) launched the theory of the Germanic village community. The period of historical hypothesis was succeeded by one of criticism, exemplified in the work of Fustel de Coulanges, and this again by one of positive construction, in which English and German scholars have taken the lead. It is characteristic of Loria that he cites authors from each one of these periods of historical work, but that he makes them all speak with the same voice, and the voice is Loria's. Maitland, Seebohm and Vinogradoff appear among his authorities, but the picture of the early agrarian organization which he presents is sketched in innocent or wilful ignorance of all that these and other scholars have done to give significance to the facts of this stage of economic development. I do not remember to have seen in Loria's book a single mention of the tribal influences to which scholars are now inclined to look for an explanation of the most interesting and most perplexing problems of these "dark ages" of European economic history. That complex combination of political, legal, social and economic elements, which made up the life of early society, as they make up the life of society today, fades away under Loria's treatment into a colorless formula, without a breath of life in it.

Loria supposes that in this early stage of history men worked in isolation, because an ample product could so be secured; but that the growth of population led to a diminution of the per capita product, and forced men finally to associate for greater efficiency. He argues that they would not willingly thus associate themselves, but were constrained to do so by the lack of free land. This coercive association, leading to the appearance of "income as the author uses the term, involved a class distinction which showed itself in the establishment at different times of slavery or serfdom or the wage system.

« ForrigeFortsett »